The Social Shaping of Technological Revolutions
Second Machine Age
Second Machine Age or Fifth Technological Revolution? (Part 2). The periodization of history into technological revolutions: why, what, how many and when?
Second Machine Age of Fifth Technological Revolution? Different interpretations lead to different recommendations – reflections on Erik Brynjolfsson and Andrew McAfee’s book The Second Machine Age (2014)
Part Two – The periodization of history into technological revolutions: why, what, how many and when?
This is the second instalment in a series of posts (and Working Paper in progress) that reflect on aspects of Erik Brynjolfsson and Andrew McAfee’s influential book, The Second Machine Age (2014), in order to examine how different historical understandings of technological revolutions can influence policy recommendations in the present. The previous post introduced the aims of the series. Here we discuss various criteria used for identifying a technological revolution, why we undertake such an exercise in periodisations, and the key lessons to be gleaned from observing the regularities in the diffusion of technological change. Over the next few weeks, we will look at the different implications that stem from applying the ‘machine ages’ or my ‘great surges’ point of view to understanding the present moment. We will look at what we see as the virtues and limits of Brynjolfsson and McAfee’s policy proposals, and why implementing policies appropriate to the stage of development of any technological revolution have been crucial to unleashing ‘Golden Ages’ in the past.
The periodization of history into technological revolutions: why, what, how many and when?
Why examine history? What are we looking for?
History is an unwieldy mass of information that can be interpreted in multiple ways depending on the lenses used by the author. Whether focusing on political hegemony, art, or technology, the purpose of distinguishing epochs is to learn something from the past that can shed light not only on the present – but on paths into the future. This is commonly done with the intent of providing policy recommendations, for proposing action or defending inaction. Therefore, explicitly identifying the nature of the lenses used to examine history should be a pre-requisite of all such attempts.
Since the late eighteenth century, industrial power suggests three major divisions: the 19th century was a time of British dominance; most of the 20th century saw power located in the US; and starting around the 1970s-80s, with the explosive diffusion of information and communication technologies (ICT), a strong process of globalization towards a multi-polar world can be observed. One could suggest that this broad brush is what has shaped the periodizations of capitalist history made by many political scientists, historians, economic historians and economists.
The work of Brynjolfsson and McAfee fits with more recent analyses which view the ICT revolution as a radical break with the past: as a new era. As noted in the introduction, they consider the first ‘machine age’ to be a single major period ranging from the industrial revolution to the current times, in which machines replaced muscle power. According to their periodization, we are now in the beginnings of a second machine age, which involves a shift in which machines replace brain power.
A third tradition in periodization is anchored in economic scholarship. It is based on recurring changes in economic performance; in the sequence of boom and bust that seems to characterize the capitalist growth process. Among the many theorists explaining or describing these regularities there are some, such as Kuznets, who identify 15-25-year investment cycles; others, like Kondratiev, identify longer waves or cycles of 50-60 years. Subsequent authors associate such growth swings with major technical change, with Schumpeter being the most prominent.
The neo-Schumpeterian approach to long cycles
More recently, evolutionary economists and scholars of innovation, such as Freeman, Louçã, Tylecote and myself, have shifted the emphasis from looking at the variations in economic growth brought by technical change to the analysis of the technologies themselves: their interrelations, their patterns of diffusion and impact on the direction of innovation; how they lead to transformations in the organization of business and institutions; the way in which they influence employment and social life; how they change and are changed by the structure of markets; and, finally, on how government action influences their impact on the economy.
This is the approach to which I subscribe, and it is in this tradition, usually referred to as neo-Schumpeterian, that ICT can be recognized as the fifth technological revolution. In the 1920s, Kondratiev had identified three ‘long waves’, as he called them, which had already occurred, and predicted the crash of 1929 as the end of the fourth. Schumpeter followed his lead and in Business Cycles (1939), made a thorough analysis of the technologies that could be associated with each cycle. Both roughly identified two periods in the British century and two in the American. In 2001, Freeman and Louçã published As Time Goes By, where they examined each of those four long waves, plus the current fifth, in terms of the technologies involved, the key organizational paradigms and the institutional framework that shaped their diffusion. This was a break with Schumpeter’s prior assumption that ‘markets’ on their own defined the cycle and then overcame stagnation without government intervention. By this point, neo-Schumpeterians had also recognized a fifth period: the ICT revolution that began in the 1970s.
My own contributions to the periodization debate have focused on expanding the analysis of the diffusion process of each technological revolution yet further. From research into the complex interactions that have occurred during each period, I introduced the concept of techno-economic paradigms to define the new ‘common sense’ or ‘best practice’ that spreads across industries and institutions during each cycle. Further historical analysis led me to make a clear break with the notion of cycles as mere upswings and downswings of GDP, and instead to focus directly on the structure of each technological revolution, and, particularly, on the regularities in the process of its diffusion and assimilation in the economy and society. This led to the abandonment of Kondratiev’s term ‘long waves’ for that of ‘great surges of development’:
“A great surge of development is … the process by which a technological revolution and its paradigm propagate across the economy, leading to structural changes in production, distribution, communication and consumption as well as to profound and qualitative changes in society. The process evolves from small beginnings, in restricted sectors and geographic regions, and ends up encompassing the bulk of activities in the core country or countries and diffusing out towards further and further peripheries, depending on the capacity of the transport and communications infrastructures”. Perez 2002, p. 15